The idea of exchange as I see is a mechanism to let loose market
forces under a controlled environment. Setup a framework by having a set of
well-defined laws, clearly define, quantize and standardize the value of
whatever to be exchanged and finally give access to whomsoever would like to
participate in the exchange activity. Simple as that, as they say and moreover
it is , faster and cheaper than the
lawyer-intensive process of negotiating bilateral licenses for intellectual
property, the high cost of which discriminates against small companies. Too add
more adjectives; it is collaborative, transparent and meritocratic.
I would argue that it is not that simple, because we need a
solid in depth understanding of the nature of the concept ‘value’ that is being
exchanged at the exchanges. We need to understand how it varies individually
and also in groups (when coalesced together with other ‘value’). Strictly speaking, the exchange ‘value’ of
anything (let us say commodity) is not identical to its price, but represents rather
what (quantity of) other commodities it will exchange for, if traded. If that
is the case, then price is a metadata tag with which we give the commodity a
meaning in the world of finance. If we call this a notional price then the real
price at which the commodity might exchange may be different i.e. the market
price. So there is a distinction between value of a commodity (notional
price) and a market price. Identification of the notional price is very
subjective; depend on the present owner of the commodity and his/her perception
of what he owns. Typically it will be cost of production plus markup. Market price
is dependent on the demand-supply and the ability of the market participants to
pay or as modern finance will say, it is dependent on the concepts of
arbitrage-free, risk neutral valuation.
Notional price is the ‘value of a commodity’ as
determined by the owner after considering its unique characteristics, cost of
production, and owner’s perception of market swings and so on. While for
certain products (like say vegetables in the vegetable market), it is rather
simplistic representing the average quantity of human labor which is necessary
to produce them, for others like financial instruments it is little deeper. The
nominal price should not only represent the labor (all the research and other
works) needed to produce; it also has the additional task representing the risk
of that which it represents. Sometimes the price of this risk is way more than
the cost of production of a financial instrument itself. Say a stock,
which represent the risk of performance of the underlying company or a bond which
represent the credit risk of the bond issuer.
For most of the cases, be it a commodity ( like
wheat, apples, fish) or simple financial products ( like stock and bonds ) the
magnitude of the value of this risk is primarily not dependent on buyers of
this product. Yes we can argue all the sides like the perception risk
(dependent on buyer) and so on but for all practical purpose it is not, at
least not like the way insurance products are dependent on. This I think is
fundamental problem to be addressed in a healthcare exchange phenomenon or as a
matter of fact for any exchange of insurance products. Two fundamental concepts
on which insurance products values are dependent on are
· law of large
numbers (LLN) : According to
the law, the average of the results obtained from a large number of trials
should be close to the expected value, and will tend to become closer as more
trials are performed.
For example, if a
fair coin (where heads and tails come up equally often) is tossed 1,000,000
times, about half of the tosses will come up heads, and half will come up
tails. The heads-to-tails ratio will be extremely close to 1:1. However, if the
same coin is tossed only 10 times, the ratio will likely not be 1:1, and in
fact might come out far different, say 3:7 or even 0:10.
· concept of a ‘weighted probability.’: a technique to find
the total expected value of multiple events.
So let’s play this game:
- We are a small insurance company that insures 1000 people.
- Let’s say that 1 house will get flooded per year.
- So the probability of a house getting flooded is (1/1000)
- Therefore the probability of a house not getting flooded is (9999/1000)
- If a house gets flooded, we will have to pay $500,000
- Every person pays you $50 a month, $600 per year
According to the formula: (E[X] = x1p1+ x2 p2+....xkpk)
where X can take value x1 with
probability p1, value x2with probability p2.
-500,000*(1/1000) + 600*(999/1000) = -500 + 599.94 = 99.94
So we will make $99.94 on average
per person insured. Therefore you’ll make 1000*(99.94) = $99940.
The LLN guarantees stable long-term results for the averages of
some random events. For example, while a casino may lose money in a single spin
of the roulette wheel, its earnings will tend towards a predictable percentage
over a large number of spins. Any winning streak by a player will eventually be
overcome by the parameters of the game. It is important to remember that the
LLN only applies (as the name indicates) when a large number of observations
are considered. There is no principle that a small number of observations will
coincide with the expected value or that a streak of one value will immediately
be "balanced" by the others (i.e. gambler’s fallacy).
The nominal price and thus the premium amount of an insurance
product is dependent on the above two concepts which in turn is related on the
number of consumers consuming the product. This relationship is direct and will
determine the existence of the product. There is almost none or little
influence of financial economics of no arbitrage, risk neutral pricing on the
market price. Market price of an insurance product is determined by actuarial
probability, then why do we need an exchange ( in the sense NYSE
operates) like market place to manage competition. We can have a market
like the vegetable market, where there are buyers and sellers, usually buyers
do not become a seller. There exists a profitability model for insurance
product and competition for that profit is in distribution i.e. how many
consumers can you enroll.
Anything that has profitability model can be privatized or
rather to privatize any service we need to find out a profitability model.
Most common thinking is that well defined profit motive makes an organization
more efficient, reduces waste i.e. deliver more for less. On the whole this is
good for a society. This is the thinking behind privatization of the health
care industry.
I would argue this is not always true; profit motive can make an
organization more efficient but not more effective. Services , not only health
care, but those which affect a large number of people , should and will always
have certain other well defined goals other than pure profit. In that
scenario, single minded focus on profit, or marketplace built to just enhance
that will defeat the very purpose of the existence of the service.
There should be a balance, while controlling costs,
organizations should try to meet all the goals to justify its existence. Not
sacrifice everything to the altar of profit and costs.
It is for this reason I believe that healthcare insurance and
many other similar services in involving a large number of people should be
semi private. Slight privatization will bring in the cost efficiency while the
part public will harness motivation of providing quality service with other
more larger goals in mind.
No comments:
Post a Comment